Democracy and Democratization
Modernization theory
- Lipset (1959): modernization theory; correlation between social and
economic development and democracy i.e. “the more well-to-do a nation,
the greater the chances it will sustain democracy”; education; democracy
arises due to its functional fit with the advanced industrial economy;
it is the middle class that is seen as the primary promoter of democracy
(by rewarding moderates and punishing extremists) while the upper class
and especially the lower class are seen as enemies of democracy; crises
of legitimacy occur during a transition to a new social structure
i.e. if the “status” of major conservative institutions is threatened
during the period of structural change; “entry-into-politics” crisis of
new social groups e.g. workers, colonies, etc.
- W. W. Rostow (1960): “anti-communist manifesto”; “stages of growth”
(e.g. “preconditions for take-off”)
- Deutsch (1961): social mobilization (social-psychological);
modernization; social mobilization; democratization
- Almond and Verba (1963): the modernization of participatory “civic
(political) culture” driven by economic development (education)
Tensions in modernization theory (structuralist
approaches)
- Gerschenkron (1962): relative backwardness and obstacles to
“catching up”; delays allow social tensions to develop
- Moore (1966): “no bourgeoisie, no democracy”; constellation of
class-relations leads to different (multiple) pathways (i.e. political
regime as DV); democracy realized in the alliance between commercialized
landowners and industrialized proletariat i.e. the bourgeoisie
ultimately avoided becoming the subordinate partner in an alliance with
landed elites against the peasantry because landed elites were weakened
or displaced during a revolutionary period in which agriculture and/or
politics was transformed; also (1) violent past (2) strong and
independent Parliament (3) commercial and industrial interest with its
own economic base (4) no serious peasant problem (already taken care of
in Britain via enclosures rather than labor-repression)
- Huntington (1968): “gap hypothesis”; economic development and
political stability are two independent goals and progress toward one
has no necessary connection with progress toward the other; in fact,
economic development may undermine political stability (e.g. rate of
modernization)
- Gunder Frank (1970): the development of underdevelopment was and
still is generated by the very same historical process(es) which also
generated economic development (capitalism itself)
- Rueschemeyer, Stephens and Stephens (1992): democratic development
requires the development of industrial capitalism, which shifts the
balance of class power away from anti-democratic landed interests and
toward reliably pro-democratic urban interests (1) class coalitions (2)
autonomy of the state apparatus (3) impact of transnational power
relations; working class as pro-democratic and upper classes as
anti-democratic (making new political coalitions possible to support
democracy)
Contingency in democratization
- D. Rustow (1970): “there may be many roads to democracy” relying on
(1) prior sense of community (national unity) (2) entrenched conflict
(3) democratic rules (4) habituation of rules; assembled one at a time
with its own logic; BUT need not be geographically uniform; need not be
temporally uniform; need not be socially uniform; polarization rather
than pluralism; backward and forward linkages (not all at once); phases
of democratization (1) background conditions (2) nature of the struggle
(3) negotiated resolution (4) habituation (consolidation)
- O’Donnell and Schmitter (1986): “there is no transition whose
beginning is not the consequence—direct or indirect—of important
divisions within the authoritarian regime itself”; transitions are
contingent periods (processes) of “undetermined” political change (1)
political opening (2) potential backlash (3) leading to “pacted
transition” between soft-liners and hard-liners (elites) (4)
institutionalization
- R. Collier (1999): strategic interaction of elite negotiations based
on class alignments (1) rising middle-class (2) mobilization of
lower-class (3) joint project between middle-class and allies (never the
working class alone); (1) class (2) prior inclusion (3) arena of action;
democratization as the adoption of three institutional attributes of
democracy (1) universal male suffrage (2) an autonomous legislature (3)
civil liberties; what were the coalitional dynamics underpinning the
many other less visible institutional reforms that occurred before the
threshold of democracy was crossed?
- Huntington (1991): “third wave” (1974-) caused by global economic
growth, decrease of legitimacy of authoritarian regimes, Catholic
emphasis on individual right; demonstration (snowball) effects;
democracy promotion (US & EU); interactions between (1) government
and opposition (2) reformers and standpatters (3) moderates and
extremists (elites and elite-splits from the top-down)
- Carothers (2002): “the end of the transition paradigm”; Case (1996)
“Can the ‘Halfway House’ Stand?”
Definitions of democracy
- J. S. Mill (1861): the government of the whole people by the whole
people, equally represented, BUT democracy is commonly conceived and
hitherto practiced by a mere majority of the people, exclusively
represented i.e. a government of privilege, in favor of the numerical
majority, who alone possess practically any voice in the State; debate
over franchise expansion
- Schumpeter (1942): procedural definition of competition; “the
democratic method is that institutional arrangement for arriving at
political decisions in which individuals acquire the power to decide by
means of a competitive struggle for the people’s vote”
- Dahl (1956/1971): contestation (competition and pluralism) and mass
participation; “polyarchy”; democracy requires not only free, fair, and
competitive elections, but also freedoms that make them meaningful
(inclusive suffrage, freedom of expression, etc.); different classes and
actors may be influential at different stages
- D. Rustow (1970): “a system of rule by temporary majorities” (the
habit of dissension and conciliation over ever-changing issues and
amidst ever-changing alignments)
- Przeworski (1990) : “democracy is a system in which parties lose
elections”
- Collier and Levitsky (1997): expanded procedural minimum; democracy
+ (1) effective power to rule (2) some social level of equality (3)
concern with authoritarian tendencies (4) horizontal accountability
(checks on executive power)
Democracy and development
- Lipset (1959) (1) endogenous democratization: development increases
the likelihood that poor countries will undergo a transition to
democracy (2) exogenous democratization: development makes democracy,
once established, less likely to fall to dictatorships
- Haggard and Kaufman (1995): it was the dismal economic performance
of most dictatorships that led to democratic transitions i.e. the
effects of economic crisis on regime change or political demands for
liberalization
- Weingast (1997): “democratic stability as a self-enforcing
equilibrium” (formal model); society must erect institutions that assure
that groups will cooperate to prevent the sovereign from transgressing;
(1) procedural and substantive limits on government
(institutionalization) (2) a citizenry willing to defend those limits
(3) the expectation among rival political parties that each will adhere
to the democratic rules
- Przeworski & Limongi (1997): exogenous modernization theory =
once democratization has occurred, it survives in countries above a
certain level of economic development; the observed relationship between
democracy and development is caused not so much by the greater
likelihood that more developed countries will democratize as by the
improbability of authoritarian interventions in developed countries
(income levels affect the likelihood of democratic breakdown but not the
probability of democratization)
- Przeworski, et al. (2000): see: above
- Boix and Stokes (2003): exogenous and endogenous modernization
theory = rising levels of income are associated with both higher
probabilities of transitions to democracy and lower probabilities of
democratic failures; Przeworski and Limongi suffer from omitted variable
bias, sample selection bias, and small sample size; earlier (first) wave
of democratization in Western Europe reveals a large endogenous effect
(economic growth increases the incentives for the ruling faction to
democratize); income equality causes dictatorships to fall and
democracies to last
- Acemoglu and Robinson (2006): social choices are inherently
conflictual between elites and citizens; “Occam’s razor” i.e. parsimony;
as income inequality rises, democracy’s costs for the wealthy increase,
lowering the probability of democratic transitions; political
institutions regulate the future allocation of political power between
various social groups; most moves toward democracy happen in the face of
significant social conflict and possible threat of revolution
- Dunning (2008): oil impedes democratization in countries with low
levels of inequality, but hastens democratization in countries with high
inequality levels by alleviating the concern of wealthy elites that
democracy will lead to the expropriation of their private assets
e.g. pro-democratic effects in Latin America but antidemocratic effects
in the rest of the world; oil is highly conditional on a host of
contextual factors; Ross (2012) = regime stability after post-1979
rents; Haber and Menaldo (2011) = no resource curse but omitted variable
bias (temporary revenue windfalls might make a dictator more popular in
the short run but be insufficient to protect him from democratic forces
when revenues fall)
- Cheibub, et al. (2010): measures of democracy; democracy
vs. dictatorship; Freedom House (political rights and civil liberties);
Polity IV (executive authority and political participation); problems
with coding (categorical, continuous, or ordinal); minimalist definition
of “offices” filled by “contested” elections links political regimes to
outcomes, raises the issue of classification (again)
Democracy and regime type
- Linz and Stepan (1996): different nondemocratic regimes
characterized by different institutional properties; establishing
democracy as “the only game in town”; consolidated democracy requires
“stateness” (including civil society, political society, rule of law,
state bureaucracy, and an institutionalized economic society/politically
regulated market); impact of the prior regime on the democratic
transition; consolidation of democratic rule; (1) inclusive and equal
citizenship (2) leadership structure of prior regime and/or transition
(3) international context (4) economic conditions (5) constitutional
environment
- O’Donnell (1994): “delegative democracy” rests on the premise that
whoever wins election to the presidency is thereby entitled to govern as
he or she sees fit, constrained only by the hard facts of existing power
relations and by a constitutionally limited term of office gives the
president the apparent advantage of having practically no horizontal
accountability; swift policy making; higher likelihood of gross
mistakes, hazardous implementation, and concentrated responsibility
- Collier and Levitsky (1997): Sartori (1970) “ladder of generality”
vs. “diminished” sub-types (e.g. “illiberal democracy”) BUT sub-types of
democracy or authoritarianism?
- Geddes (1999): different kinds of authoritarianism break down in
different ways (personalist, military, single-party); military regimes
have more endogenous sources of instability and are more fragile;
single-party regimes have few endogenous sources of instability and can
weather the death of leaders; BUT regime transitions of all kinds are
more likely during economic downturns
- Levitsky and Way (2002): possibility of “hybrid regimes”
i.e. competitive authoritarianism; arenas of contestation (1) electoral
arena (2) legislature (3) judiciary (4) media; decay of an authoritarian
regime; collapse of an authoritarian regime; decay of democratic regime;
regime consolidation requires elite cohesion and a minimally
effective—and financially solvent—state apparatus
Patterns of democracy
- Lijphart (1977): “consociationalism” = fragmented but stable
democracy; (1) grand coalition (2) mutual veto (3) PR (4) segmental
autonomy (5) shared executive; internal political cohesion of the
subcultures, adequate articulation of interests, approval of elite
cartel
- Horowitz (1993): ethno-national divides; inclusion vs. exclusion and
subsequent polarization; democratic institutions may lead to
undemocratic results; majority rule vs. minority exclusion; federal
solutions to democratization; case study of Nigeria and India;
devolution of power to homogenous federal units reduces conflict at the
center and contests issues within ethnic groups rather than between
them; ethnic power-sharing vs. federal solutions (PR
vs. majoritarian)
- Putnam (1993): sub-national regional variation in Italy; governments
performed best where there were strong traditions of civic engagement;
social capital; trust bridging different groups; differences in medieval
governing structures
- Lijphart (1999): majoritarian vs. consensus (negotiated) democracy;
executives-parties dimension and federal-unitary dimension; consensus
democracy in plural societies that are sharply divided along religious,
ideological, linguistic, cultural, ethnic, or racial lines into
virtually separate sub-societies with their own political parties,
interest groups, and media of communication
Historical democratization
- Capoccia (2005): in Belgium, Czechoslovakia and Finland the
political elite managed to react effectively against severe
anti-democratic threats by isolating the extremists and using both
repressive and inclusive strategies; the high degree of political
intolerance against the extremists generally reached in these
democracies was in fact accompanied byparallel attempts to integrate
some of them back into the system
- Capoccia and Ziblatt (2010): historically, democracy did not emerge
as a singular coherent whole but rather as a set of different
institutions, which resulted from conflicts across multiple lines of
social and political cleavage that took place at different moments in
time; institutional building blocks of democracy emerged
asynchronically; analytically interesting “near misses”; underestimate
the importance of the actual unfolding of the strategic interaction that
led to the establishment or the reshaping of democratic
institutions
- Ziblatt (2017): a robust conservative political party organization
can unleash a self-reinforcing virtuous cycle of electoral competition
and open-endedness in electoral outcomes, prompting democracy’s
advocates to ratchet up their own mobilizational capacity to meet the
challenge; a robust conservative political party may actually be a
precondition for democracy
Authoritarianism
Early literature
- Arendt (1951/1966): defines totalitarian systems as differentiated
based on the use of terror (role of police, coercion, violence, etc.);
the state uses propaganda to create a largely fictional narrative that
submerges individual and collective interests within an overriding
national struggle
- O’Donnell (1973): “modernization and bureaucratic-authoritarianism”;
to neutralize the threats to their rule that emerge from within society,
autocrats attempt to co-opt or “encapsulate” the potential opposition
i.e. the career patterns and power bases of most incumbents of
technocratic roles; bureaucratic-authoritarianism arises in Brazil and
Argentina because of (1) growing political weight of lower middle- and
working-class groups (2) the appearance of economic bottlenecks, and
increased significance of technocratic roles (3) horizontal industrial
growth of the two countries, based on consumer goods, ISI, and expansion
of domestic market; basis for populist coalitions that encouraged
economic and political incorporation of popular sector; if the
government is not successful in applying coercion, popular sector and
domestic entrepreneurs can strike, demonstrate, or riot
- O’Donnell and Schmitter (1986): “there is no transition whose
beginning is not the consequence—direct or indirect—of important
divisions within the authoritarian regime itself”; thus opening the lens
of analysis to elite cleavages within the authoritarian regime;
liberalization can exist without democratization (putting democratic
principles into practice) i.e. two different variables; hard-liners
vs. soft-liners; the “cycle of mobilization”; degree of militarization;
negotiation of “pacts” (series of temporary arrangements) that may in
fact subsequently impede democratic consolidation
- Luebbert (1991): (1) interwar liberal democracy rested on a
coalition of the center-right stabilized by the political isolation of
the working classes and by the ineffectiveness of trade union
organizations in liberal societies (2) social democratic political
economies, by contrast, rested during the interwar years on alliances of
the urban working classes and the family or middle peasantry (a
democratic version of corporatism) (3) fascism repudiated both the
politics and the economics of liberalism, substituting totalitarianism,
or some approximation of it, for democratic competition, resting on a
social coalition of the town and country (one that combined the family
peasantry with the urban middle classes rather than the urban working
classes)
- Wintrobe (1998): autocrats are fundamentally interested in their own
survival in power; if autocrats rely too much on terror, repression, and
intimidation to sustain their rule, they become more vulnerable to
agency and moral-hazard problems on the part of their own security
apparatus, upon which their ability to survive ultimately depends
- Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003): dictators do not face a general
threat from the rest of society, but instead face a threat from a subset
called the “selectorate”;
- Haber (2006): in order to rule the country, autocrats have to bestow
resources on elite members, who, in turn, can use these same resources
to overthrow the regime
Authoritarianism as a regime type
- Linz (2000): “authoritarian regimes” differentiated by limited
pluralism and popular mobilization, in contrast with totalitarian and
democratic regimes; hinting at the the role of limited and uncompetitive
elections as a tool to maintain elite cohesion and facilitate elite
recruitment; i.e. “authoritarian regimes” care what people do” as
opposed to “totalitarian regimes,” which care what people think
while
- Levitsky and Way (2002): literature suffers from a “democratizing
bias”; competitive authoritarianism where there are formal democratic
institutions, but incumbents violate these rules so often that the
regime fails to meet conventional minimal standards for democracy
- Way (2005): autocrat competitiveness within the regime; incumbent
capacity (1) authoritarian state power (2) know-how (3) elite
organization; anti-incumbent national identity (1) central state control
(2) utility/availability of external support; weaknesses (1) open elite
contestation (2) administrative resources (3) vulnerability to
democratizing pressures
- Howard and Roessler (2006): “liberalizing electoral outcome”; the
political opposition can affect the electoral dynamic depending on
whether it (1) creates a multiparty coalition or jointly supports a
single candidate (2) initiates mobilization (antigovernment
protests)
- Way (2015): “pluralism by default”; in many cases, democratic
contestation has persisted because autocrats have been too weak to steal
elections, reprise opposition, or keep allies in line; leaders lack the
resources, authority, or coordination to prevent today’s allies from
becoming tomorrow’s challengers, to control the legislature, impose
censorship, manipulate elections, or use forced against political
opponents; (1) disorganization (2) divided national identity; lead to
(1) low electoral manipulation (2) strong parliamentary power (3)
powerful opposition (4) media pluralism
Electoral authoritarianism
- Schedler (2002): “menu of manipulation”; access to the electoral
arena always has a cost and is never perfectly equal; the distinction
between obeying and transgressing democratic norms is imprecise; splits
in the party system; redistributive practices (electoral fraud); rules
of representation (institutional bias); and the norm of
irreversibility
- Magaloni (2006): “one-party rule” and large margins of victory (PRI
in Mexico); more than using legislatures, dictators can use institutions
within the ruling party in order to make credible inter-temporal
power-sharing deals with potential elite opponents; the party controls
succession and access-to-power positions; In Mexico, the ruling party’s
central leadership controlled the nomination processes and, owing to a
system of non-reelection for all competitive offices, the party could
induce strong discipline from subnational office-seekers who had an
incentive to align with the party leadership and with the president to
obtain access to future rent-seeking positions; moreover, the regime
strove to create “poverty traps” and systems of dependency with rural
voters, who remained the PRI’s base of support until the deterioration
of economic conditions; later, perceptions about the possibility of
post-election violence changed and facilitated greater support for
opposition parties
- Gandhi and Przeworkski (2007): autocrats face threats that emerge
from (1) within the ruling elite (2) outsiders within society; when they
need to neutralize threats from larger groups, autocrats frequently rely
on nominally democratic institutions; partisan legislatures incorporate
potential opposition forces, investing them with a stake in the ruler’s
survival; and last longer
- Gandhi and Lust-Okar (2009): ruling elites also can manipulate the
rules that shape voter and candidate behavior in elections; in
selectively co-opting the opposition and manipulating electoral laws,
dictators also create divided oppositions and increase coordination
costs among their opponents; at the local level, corruption seems to be
intended not so much to win elections as to show the ruling elites that
the local officials can get out the vote (e.g. Russian regional
governors); see
- Brownlee (2011): executive elections constitute a part of
authoritarian resilience in MENA; function as both a political safety
valve and performative aspect i.e. “window dressing” (“patronage fetes,
and regime exhibitions”); but need some competition and turnout
(Egypt)
- Svolik (2012): power sharing under authoritarianism is sustained by
the ability of each side to punish the other party if it decides to
deviate from that joint-governance arrangement and, in particular, by
the credible threat of a rebellion by the ruler’s allies; authoritarian
control vs. authoritarian power-sharing; reliance on repression creates
a moral hazard
- Morse (2012): “the era of electoral authoritarianism”; electoral
fraud as indicative of regime breakdown and greater oppositional
capacity or of conditions that have compelled incumbents to engage in
such fraudulent practices to begin with; lesser fraud can be seen as a
sign of regime confidence in its capacity to win elections, leading to
elections that are more competitive in terms of the actual contestation
but less amenable to oppositions; not whether fraud plays a role or not
in electoral outcomes but, rather, under what conditions regimes are
likely to use it more often and intensively
- Schedler (2013): “the politics of uncertainty”; “elections as
adornments” (Brownlee, 2007); “elections as tools” (Gandhi, 2008);
“elections as arenas” (Schedler, 2013); authoritarian regimes suffer
from institutional and informational uncertainties and use elections to
overcome these unknowns
Democratic backsliding
- Linz (1978/1990): the breakdown of democratic regimes; political
agency and voluntarism i.e. the role of leadership and incumbents in
carrying out actions that could defuse regime crises; declining
authoritarian regime legitimacy; presidential systems more prone to
political crisis and democratic breakdown (1) legitimacy (2/3)
efficacy/effectiveness (4) stability and performance
- Fish (2002): super-presidentialism; power-seeking presidents
unconstrained by powerful institutions or competing centers of power
initiate backsliding
- Gibler and Randazzo (2011): the effects of independent judiciaries
on the likelihood of democratic backsliding; judicial review as
mechanism of horizontal accountability
- Ahmed (2014): the concept of backsliding as it is conventionally
used implies a theoretical move back on an imagined linear trajectory;
apparently exclusionary measures can further democratization, allowing
regime stability necessary for further strengthening or, at other times,
providing focal points or mobilizing narratives around which political
forces rally, pressing for more democratic measures; certain safeguards
that could be viewed as backsliding in some cases may, in fact, help to
strengthen and consolidate democracy in the long run
- Mainwaring and Pérez-Liñán (2014): (1) the degree of radicalism of
policy preferences (2) normative commitment to democracy; democracies
whose leaders have radical policy preferences or lack normative
commitments to democracy, or both, will be more fragile and vulnerable
to breakdown; these democracies might also be vulnerable to backsliding,
as actors may seek their policy goals without formally abolishing
democracy
- Lust and Waldner (2014): backsliding may occur when party systems
are unbalanced, with some parties being organizationally weak and others
strong
- Levitsky and Ziblatt (2018): “how democracies die” (1) rejection of
(or weak commitment to) democratic rules of the game (2) denial of the
legitimacy of political opponents (3) toleration of encouragement of
violence (4) readiness to curtail civil liberties of opponents,
including media; successful gatekeeping requires mainstream parties to
isolate and defeat extremist forces e.g. resist putting populists on the
ballot who can potentially deliver votes, root out grass roots
extremists, avoid all alliances with anti-democratic parties and
candidates, isolate rather than legitimize extremists; must be willing
to join with opponents ideologically distant but committed to the
survival of the democratic political order
Bureaucratic monitoring in authoritarian regimes
- Kuran (1991): “cascades”; the possibility that a protest today spurs
more protests tomorrow by revealing information about the degree of
popular support for the regime; attributed to the heterogeneous
tolerance for “preference falsification” among the population
- Triesman (2011): although media manipulation, wars, terrorist
attacks, and other events also mattered, Putin’s unprecedented
popularity and the decline in Yeltsin’s are well explained by the
contrasting economic circumstances over which each presided
- Reuter and Robinson (2012): the appointment of Russian governors
depends on their ability to mobilize votes for the regime; and
cooptation in Russian gubernatorial appointments, as governors with
strong political machines were more likely to be reappointed
initially
- Lorentzen (2013) authoritarian regimes may in fact benefit from
localized, limited protests, as by doing so they gather information that
is otherwise hard to collect in the absence of competitive elections or
free media
- Little (2016) distinguishes between models in which the regime uses
elections to gather information about its popular support (gather
information) versus models in which elections signal the regime’s hold
on power to external audiences (signal strength); within authoritarian
regimes, institutions like parties, elections and legislatures are
positively correlated with good outcomes like economic growth,
investment, and even life expectancy (Miller, 2015); in the
information-gathering model, the incumbent holds an election if k <
delta_g + delta_v; delta_g is high when the regime gets a much higher
payoff when making the optimal concession (given what they have learned
from the election result) than they would being unresponsive to the
election; that is, when the information gathered by the election is
useful for choosing how much to concede e.g. providing information not
only about the incumbent strength in an entire country, but by region
(Blaydes, 2010), polling station, or even individual vote choices; on
average, the presence of elections as a tool to simply signal strength
harms regimes (the more elections are held, the fewer resources the
regime has to spend on other ways to stay in power)
- Gelbach and Simpser (2014): “electoral manipulation as bureaucratic
control”; by influencing bureaucrats’ beliefs about the ruler’s hold on
power, manipulation can encourage bureaucrats to work on behalf of the
ruler when they would not otherwise do so; to cooperate with the ruler
even when the citizen may not be responsive to bureaucratic effort
- Rundlett and Svolik (2016): even if the infrastructure of fraud
favors the incumbent, his genuine popularity still plays a crucial role
in shaping the agents’ perception of the risk of engaging in fraud;
electoral authoritarianism should therefore be characterized by a
punctuated dynamic, with an oversupply of fraud that lasts as long as
the incumbent enjoys genuine popularity and is interrupted by an
undersupply of fraud as soon as that popularity dwindles
- Reuter et al. (2016): autocrats can use local elections to assuage
powerful subnational elites; when subnational elites control significant
political resources, such as local political machines, leaders may need
to co-opt them to govern cost-effectively; elections are an effective
tool of co-optation because they provide elites with autonomy and the
opportunity to cultivate their own power bases
Corruption
Corrupt structures
- Darden (2007): graft often serves as a form of unofficial
compensation that reinforces rather than undermines the formal
institutions of the state, and can provide leaders with additional means
to control subordinate officials; graft may reinforce administrative
hierarchies
- Ziblatt (2009): shaping democratic practice and the causes of
electoral fraud (Germany); electoral fraud’s incidence is significantly
related to a society’s level of inequality in landholding; landed elites
exert influence indirectly via the capture of rural local public
officials such as mayors, county commissioners, police officials, and
election officials, who in turn are the actors that interfere with free
and fair elections
- Hale (2014): patronal politics refers to politics in societies where
individuals organize their political and economic pursuits primarily
around the personalized exchange of concrete rewards and punishments
through chains of actual acquaintance; regime dynamics depend upon how
patronal networks are arranged (1) “single pyramid” (2) “multiple,
usually competing pyramids”
- Kenny (2015): (1) greater centrifugal and disintegrative pressures
at key moments in the state-building process give local elites more
opportunity to institutionalize patronage at the subnational level (2)
decentralized patronage systems are more resistant to reform than
centralized ones; occurs where democratization precedes
professionalization of the bureaucracy and mass mobilization by
political parties
Corrupt actors
- Stokes and Dunning, et al. (2013): strategies of clientelism,
machine politics, and patronage as nonprogrammatic distributive
strategies; clientelism = (1) patronage (2) vote buying (turnout buying)
vs. partisan bias = (1) non-conditional benefits to individuals (2)
pork-barrel politics; distributive politics should, in theory, favor
swing districts but loyal individuals; information gathered and provided
via intermediaries called “brokers” that solve information problems for
political machines
- Bussell (2015): distinguishing between individuals with different
corrupt incentives and different types of state resources (welfare
benefits, natural resources, and public contracts); necessary to
identify who has power over these resources; middlemen may exert
informal influence in the distribution of resources; (1) legislative (2)
contracting (3) employment (4) services
- Mares (2015): examines how the 1903 German legislation that
introduced ballot envelopes and isolating spaces affected the strength
of support for the Social Democratic Party, the major anti-system party
in Germany; prior to the introduction of this legislation, support for
the party had been suppressed through intimidation by employers and
state employees i.e. the legislation protected voter secrecy by giving
voters the opportunity to support the opposition party without fearing
layoffs
- Mares and Young (2016): clientelism is an exchange relationship;
positive rewards; negative threats of economic or physical sanctions;
the protection of voter secrecy affects clientelistic strategies;
threats of post-electoral punishments of voters are extremely powerful
if electoral secrecy is imperfectly protected; see: Mares (2015)
- Auerbach (2016): clientelistic networks vary in their density and
partisan balance across communities, with important consequences for the
provision of public services (1) in slums with dense party networks,
competition among party workers generates a degree of accountability in
local patron-client hierarchies that encourages development (2)
politicians are less likely to extend services to slums with multiparty
networks because opposing networks can enjoy the services and even take
credit for their provision; within settlements, partisan competition can
also create perverse incentives for rival networks to undermine each
other’s development efforts
Federalism
Origins of federalism
- Riker (1964): the “federal bargain”; “coming-together” federations
(1) expand territorial control in the face of (2) external
military-diplomatic threats; the survival of a federation was
problematic in the absence of a centralized party system to help
coordinate behavior across levels of government and minimize
intergovernmental conflict; centralized into unitary states
vs. peripheralized into state collapse; the “essence” of federalism is
(1) the political bargain (2) the distribution of power in political
parties which shapes the federal structure; i.e. the role of state-wide
parties
- Stepan (1999/2001): “coming-together” federations e.g. USA and
Switzerland vs. “holding-together” federations e.g. India, Belgium,
Spain; “putting-together” federations e.g. USSR; “demos-constraining”
federations (Riker) vs. “demos-enabling” federations aimed at “holding
together” former empires or colonies
- ZIblatt (2004): infrastructural capacity (Mann) of the federal
sub-units (1) high infrastructural subunits that are constitutional,
parliamentary, and administratively modernized states can serve as
credible negotiating partners, deliver the benefits that state builders
seek with state formation in the first place (greater tax revenue,
greater access to military manpower, and greater social stability), and
hold on to some of their own autonomy (2) political leaders in
constituent states facing government collapse are willing to transfer
all authority to the political center because they perceive that public
goods of governance are more assured in a larger unitary state
Fiscal federalism
- Rodden (2004/2005): fiscal decentralization vs. federalism; federal
and provincial governments locked into an ongoing process of
intergovernmental contracting; federalism is best understood not as a
particular distribution of authority between governments, but rather a
process structured by a set of institutions through which authority is
distributed and re-distributed; bargaining between levels as
decentralization may cede or restrict
- Treisman (1999/2006): territorially larger but not necessarily more
populous countries are more fiscally decentralized; former colonies of
Spain or Portugal are more centralized, while former Soviet states are
particularly decentralized; economic development leads to greater
expenditure on decentralization; the survival of Russia in the aftermath
of the fall of communism was due in large part to that nation’s federal
arrangements and the national government’s capacity to purchase the
acquiescence of separatist regions with fiscal transfers
Federal party systems
- Chhibber and Coleman (2004): party systems are shaped by social
cleavages, electoral rules, political entrepreneurs, and a fourth
element that interacts with all three of these others and creates
incentives for candidates and elected officials to link voters in
disparate geographic locations under common party labels; the
distribution of authority across different levels of government;
federalism and the degree of fiscal and political centralization play a
large role in party aggregation
- Bakke and Wibbels (2006): fiscal decentralization increases the
likelihood of ethnic rebellion and ethnic protest in contexts where
there are high levels of interregional inequality; increased fiscal
transfers by central governments to decentralized governments serve to
reduce the likelihood of ethnic protest when ethnic groups are
regionally concentrated; local violence is more likely when minorities
are not electorally valuable
Subnationalism
- Gibson (2005): “subnational authoritarianism”; democratic
transitions create little pressure for subnational democratization (1)
parochialization of power (2) nationalization of influence (3)
monopolization of national-subnational linkages;
- Mickey (2015): “the democratization of authoritarian enclaves in
America’s deep south” (Gibson)
- Singh (2016): “how solidarity works for welfare”; subnational
governments that have a stronger collective identification are more
likely to institute a progressive social policy and have higher welfare
outcomes; elite sub-nationalism is spread to the people at large through
a popular movement and/or an organization, such as a political party;
subnational symbols; subnational identity; strategies of subnational
challenger elites provoke response e.g. Kerala Communist cadres
mobilized against Brahmin dominance e.g. Uttar Pradesh Hindi elites
distinct from Muslim-Urdu identities
State-nations
- Linz and Stepan (1992): political identities and electoral sequences
(1) Spain (2) Soviet Union (3) Yugoslavia; elections create agendas,
actors, identities; legitimate and delegitimate claims to obedience and
create power; regional elections in the USSR and Yugoslavia did all
these things; Spain the process set in motion by all-union general
elections reconstituted state-ness on even firmer grounds; regional
elections in the USSR and Yugoslavia did the opposite
- Stepan, Linz, and Yadav (2010): “state-nations”; asymmetrical
“holding-together” federations; individual and collective rights;
parliamentary government; polity-wide parties; politically integrated
but not necessarily culturally assimilated populations; cultural
nationalists mobilizing against secessionist nationalists; pattern of
multiple but complimentary identities i.e. “roof of rights”
e.g. India
- O’Leary (2013): “power sharing in deeply divided places” case
studies e.g. Northern Ireland, Lebanon, Switzerland, etc.
Identity
Nationalism
- E. Weber (1976): “peasants into Frenchmen”; via the penetration of
the state (1) roads (2) classrooms (3) post offices
- Anderson (1983/1991): nationalism as an imagined political community
(1) inherently limited (2) sovereign
- Gellner (1983): nationalism is the general imposition of a high
culture on society where previously low cultures had taken up the lives
of the majority and in some cases the totality of the population;
nationalism usually conquers in the name of a putative folk culture
defined in terms of the age of nationalism
- Brubaker (1992): “cultural idioms”; ways of thinking and talking
about nationhood; (1) state-centered and assimilationist in France (2)
ethnocultural and differentialist in Germany; reinforced and activated
in specific historical and institutional settings; nation as a category
of practice; interplay between (1) nationalizing minorities (2)
nationalizing states (3) external national homelands; Soviet nationality
policy
Ethnicity
- Horowitz (1985): ethnicity based on a myth of collective ancestry
which usually carries with it traits believed to be innate; ethnically
diverse societies are prone to corruption, political instability, poor
institutional performance, and slow economic growth
- Fearon and Latin (1996): given weak states and cultural pluralism,
communal violence is extremely rare in Africa; interethnic violence is
contained because of in-group policing; interethnic cooperation is
sustained by the expectations people have about what will happen if they
cheat
- Varshney (2002): (1) essentialism i.e. ethnic conflicts today can be
traced back to older animosities between groups (2) instrumentalism
i.e. building bridges may be in the interest of the political elite at
one place and creating cleavages in their interest elsewhere (3)
constructivism i.e. post-modernism: the construction of group categories
by the knowledge elite, its promotion by centers of power, and its
effects on “the people” (4) institutionalism i.e. institutions do not
simply specify procedures, rules, and sites for political contestation;
they also begin to generate predispositions to outcomes, given the
number and size of ethnic groups
- Posner (2004/2005): ethnicity as a strategic choice; the cleavage
that emerges as salient is the aggregation of all actors’ individual
decisions about the identity that will serve them best; tribal
identities are important in villages but linguistic ones are important
in urban areas; if the cultural cleavage defines groups that are large
enough to constitute viable coalitions in the competition for political
power, then politicians will mobilize these groups and the cleavage that
divides them will become politically salient i.e. “size matters” in
Malawi (groups large enough to be contenders) and Zambia (too small to
form winning coalitions); in Zambia identity was expressed in localized
tribal affiliations under one-party rule and in larger linguistic
identities under multi-party rule (minimum winning coalition)
- Chandra (2006): (1) constrained change (2) visibility; impersonal
(imagined community); sectionalism; eligibility; genetics and
ancestry
Public goods provisions
- Miguel (2004): natural experiment; similar geography and histories
in Kenya and Tanzania but radically different nation-building policies
since independence; ethnic diversity leads to lower public goods funding
in Kenya but is not associated with poor collective action outcomes in
Tanzania where nation-building polices improved interethnic
cooperation
- Lieberman (2005): strong boundary institutions may reduce intergroup
contacts but more important, promote perception of limited
cross-boundary contact; weak boundary institutions lead to pooling of
risk because one does not know how a particular issue will affect their
ethnic group; response to AIDS across African states; ethnic divisions
lead to weak policy responses because (1) more highly affected groups
did not lobby for action (out of concern for their relative social
status i.e. stigmatization) (2) less highly affected groups falsely
consider themselves insulated and fail to act (due to the way people
estimate risks in divided societies)
- Banjeree et al. (2005): social divisions in India lead to poor
policy outcomes in India vs. Singh (2016)
- Habyarimana et al. (2007): social interaction is a game comprising
(1) a population (2) a technology (3) preferences; co-ethnics tend to
cooperate under a norm of in-group reciprocity; co-ethnics may be more
likely to punish each other for failing to cooperate; more likely to
favor each other and cooperate if they are seen doing so; no evidence
that ethnic groups in have tastes for different kinds of public goods or
that individuals exhibit greater degrees of altruism toward co-ethnics
or co-ethnics are not significantly more effective at working together
on joint tasks e.g. Uganda
Mobilization
- Dunning and Harrison (2010): cross-cutting ties afforded by an
informal institution called cousinage can help explain limited political
salience of ethnic identity in Mali; subjects favor coethnics over
politicians from different ethnic groups; however, cousinage alliances
counteract the negative impact of ethnic differences on candidate
evaluations
- Arriola (2012/2013): multiethnic opposition coalitions are most
likely to emerge where incumbents have lost influence over the political
allegiance of business elites because of liberalizing financial sector
reforms; asymmetry in access to resources between incumbent and
opposition determines coalition formation; opposition parties obtain
monetary support from business leaders, which in turn allows opposition
leaders to provide money, favors, and goods in exchange for the
endorsements of politicians from other ethnic backgrounds
- McCauley (2014): updating of Posner (2005); politicians are not the
only ones attuned to the logic of ethnic arithmetic; just as politicians
seek to build coalitions of viable sizes, voters also seek to gain entry
into coalitions that will permit each one of their own to win political
power (1) when individuals respond in an ethnic context, they place
greater priority on material concerns and local development (2)
otherwise identical individuals placed in a religious context indicate a
relative preference for lifestyle, or morality, based social policies
over development ones; ethnic membership implies a special,
lineage-based entitlement to local territory and resources e.g. Cote
d’Ivoire and Ghana
Religion
- Wittenberg (2006): local institutions act as focal points for the
persistence of mass political loyalties (continuing electoral preference
for party family); persistent attachments to rightist parties emerged as
an outgrowth of local church-based social networks that girded their
members against pressures to succumb to the many incentives to
assimilate into the socialist milieu
- Fish (2011): Muslims are not statistically more religious, different
in terms of social interaction, or substantially more likely to favor a
fusion of religious and political authority
- Grzymala-Busse (2012): political implications of religion (1)
hierarchies (2) political behavior and partisanship (3) civil society,
rule of law, and minimized market regulation (4) conflict between church
and state over poverty relief (5) market competition over religious
platforms
Social theories of protest
- Trotsky (1932): the mere existence of deprivation is not enough to
cause an insurrection: if it were, the masses would be always in
revolt
- Gurr (1970): “social origins of deprivation”; rising expectations;
when the people are in their most desperate and miserable condition,
they are often least inclined to revolt, for then they are hopeless;
only after their position is somewhat improved and they have sensed the
possibility of change, do they revolt effectively against oppression and
injustice; what touches off insurrection is hope, not lack of it, rising
confidence, not bleak suffering
- Scott (1976): the “moral economy of the peasant”;
subsistence-oriented peasants avoid economic disaster and risks to
maximize average income which has enormous implications for problem of
exploitation; problem of exploitation and rebellion is not just problem
of calories and income but of peasant conceptions of social justice, of
rights and obligations, and of reciprocity
- Scott (1985): “every day resistance” (1) foot-dragging (2) evasion
(3) false compliance (4) pilfering (5) feigned ignorance (6) slander and
sabotage
Resistance and mobilization
- O’Brien (1996): “rightful resistance”; form of political action in
which the people use established laws, policies, and values to show that
some officials have failed to live up to those same ideals; seek to make
allies of other leaders who must prove their own dedication to the
prescribed laws and values; between the two classical types of
resistance (1) the direct and aggressive rebellion (2) ‘’everyday
resistance’’ of subtle, anonymous, and disguised forms of dissent
- Ekiert (1996): during two periods (1) the late 1950s (2) late 1980s;
state-socialist regimes experienced profound instability caused by the
overlapping of the domestic economic and political crisis with
geopolitical pressures and uncertainty; generated splits and struggles
within the ruling elites, led to the fall of powerful leaders, and
created openings in the political space; a crisis in one country tends
to foster parallel processes in other countries and generates preemptive
responses of their ruling elites
- Tarrow (1996): “power in movement”; social movements are collective
challenges, based on common purposes and social solidarities, in
sustained interaction with elites, opponents, and authorities; “cycles
of contention” i.e. as one movement widens and information spreads about
the susceptibility of a polity to challenge, additional activists and
also ordinary people may “begin to test the limits of social control;
rely on symbols and frames e.g. inherited cultural frames
- Norris et al. (2005): protest politics has risen dramatically;
demonstrators are drawn disproportionately from the left, and the people
who demonstrate are also significantly more likely to be civic joiners,
party members, and labor organization members, not less; demonstrations
have become a major channel of public participation in democracies
- Wilkinson (2006): “electoral incentives for ethnic violence”:
interstate and town-level variation in ethnic violence in India via the
conditions under which the politicians who control the police and army
have an incentive both to foment and to prevent ethnic violence;
important political incentives when politicians in government will
increase the supply of protection to minorities (1) when minorities are
an important part of their party’s current support base (2) the support
base of one of their coalition partners in a coalition government (3)
when the overall electoral system in a state is so competitive that
there is therefore a high probability that the governing party will have
to negotiate or form coalitions with minority supported parties in the
future
- McAdam and Tarrow (2010): “dynamics of contention;”political
opportunities provide the major incentives for transforming
mobilizational potential into action; signal the vulnerability of the
state to collective action and thereby open up opportunity for others
and affecting both alliances and conflict systems; the process leads to
state responses which, in one way or another, produce a new structure of
opportunity
- Kopstein and Wittenberg (2018): “intimate violence”; “power threat”
model; pogroms were most likely to break out where Jews made up a
substantial minority of the population and there was political
polarization between Jews and non-Jews; the popularity of Polish parties
advocating ethnic tolerance, the demographic weight of Jews, and the
degree to which Jews advocated national equality with Poles and
Ukrainians
Revolution
- Skocpol (1985): (1) class-based upheavals that cause
societal-structural change (2) a coincidence of political with social
change; political crises centered in the structures and situations of
old-regime states; monarchical authorities were subjected to new threats
or to intensified competition from more economically developed powers
abroad; constrained or checked in their responses by the
institutionalized relationships of the autocratic state organizations to
the landed upper classes and the agrarian economies; cross-pressures
between domestic class structures and international exigencies, the
autocracies and their centralized administrations and armies broke
apart, opening the way for social-revolutionary transformations
spearheaded by revolts from below
- Kuran (1991): the element of “surprise”; the unobservability of
private preferences and revolutionary thresholds concealed the latent
bandwagons in formation and also made it difficult to appreciate the
significance of events that were pushing these into motion; “preference
falsification”
- Way (2008): post-communist autocrats have been more likely to hold
onto power when their countries have weaker ties to the West and when
they have access to at least one of the following sources of
authoritarian organizational power (1) a single, highly
institutionalized ruling party (2) a strong coercive apparatus that has
won a major violent conflict (3) state discretionary control over the
economy, through either de jure state control or the capture of major
mineral wealth, such as oil or gas
- Finkel, Gelbach, and Olson (2015): implementation of the 1861 serf
reform was captured by the nobility; landowners abused their control
rights to “cut off” peasants’ existing land allotments, provide them
with different allotments, resettle peasants to different land entirely,
and more generally ensure that the estate’s most fertile lands would
remain in the landlord’s hands; the only thing the peasants could do in
this situation was protest and riot; capture of the implementation
process met with rising expectations i.e. “relative deprivation”
Parties and Elections
Early theories of political parties
- Madison (1787): parties as factions; a minority or majority united
by some common impulse of passion, or of interest, adverse to the rights
of other citizens, or to the permanent and aggregate interests of the
community
- Schattschneider (1942): political parties “create” democracy by
drawing the masses into political life
- Downs (1957): “median voter theorem”; spatial model of party
competition (economic theory of democracy); political parties formulate
policy in order to maximize votes, which depends on the distribution and
number of voters; knowing that citizens vote for parties that maximize
their utility, their distribution determines the policy positions of
parties; parties as internally unified around the goal of office
- Lipset and Rokkan (1967): “freezing hypothesis”; the Reformation,
national, and industrial revolutions created four cleavages (1)
center/periphery (2) religious/secular (3) urban/rural (4)
capital/labor; crystallized in European party systems; once societal
divisions have been converted into party cleavages they stay frozen over
extended periods of time even though underlying societal conflicts may
subside (1) core “nation-builders” control the machinery of the state
(2) face an opposition in the periphery opposed to the current central
control (3) seek alliances on two fronts: religious/ideological and
economic/interest
- Sartori (1968/1976): parties are parts i.e. expressive agencies;
forcefully convey to authorities demands of public as a whole; parties
extract from the whole (the public) what is desired by a part (the
party); instruments for running a pluralistic whole; presuppose
diversity and institutionalize dissent; non-part parties deny the
principle of diversity and institutionalize repression of dissent; PR
produces systems with three or more parties, depending on the number of
seats in districts and the minimum number of votes required to gain any
legislative representation (1) number of relevant parties (2) level of
ideological polarization; e.g. two-party, moderate pluralism, polarized
pluralism (presence of relevant anti-system parties), predominant
party
- Kitschelt (2000): the idea that politics is based only on rival
programmatic (ideological) appeals has been problematic; (1) charismatic
party linkages i.e. symbolic or personalistic, based on citizens’ likes
and dislikes of grand gestures and personal styles (2) clientelistic
party linkages i.e. delivering specific material advantages to a
politician’s electoral supporters (3) programmatic parties i.e. pursuit
of policy programs that distribute benefits and costs to all citizens,
regardless of whether they voted for the government of the day or not;
tension between institutional and functional definitions of parties;
some programmatic parties, in fact, are likely to serve rent-seeking
special interests, particularly in highly fragmented party systems in
which small constituencies have their own parties; where universal
suffrage is granted after industrialization has come under way, the
mobilization of proletarians excluded from the political process relies
on mass parties (Socialist, Catholic) that mobilize internal membership
resources and do not rely on clientelist state incentives; the choice of
linkage mechanisms is not just predicated on formal democratic
institutions but also on (substantive economic and political power
relations that manifest themselves in (1) socioeconomic development (2)
patterns of state formation and democratic suffrage diffusion (3)
control of the political economy by markets or political-regulatory
mechanisms
Regional party systems
- Kitschelt (1992): fluidity of property rights undercuts the
formation of economic and social cleavage divisions because citizens are
unable to recognize the interests that may serve as the basis of
political mobilization around programmatic parties; international
economic constraints imposed on liberalization leave little to choose;
new cleavage dimensions (1) boundaries of citizenship (2) participation
(3) redistribution; where economic development was relatively advanced,
more parties will concentrate on the market-libertarian end of the
competitive space; where industrialization was less advanced, more
parties cluster around non-market-authoritarian (“populist”)
positions
- Mainwairing and Scully (1995): Latin America; institutionalized
vs. inchoate party systems; party systems establish legitimacy;
institutionalized party systems promote governability by allowing
participation and conflict; facilitate governability via linkages among
the executive, legislators, and party leaders; democracy can survive
despite polarization; BUT long-standing democracies have limited
polarization
- Hale (2005): “market for parties”; Russia (1) administrative capital
(2) ideational capital; O’Donnell and Schmitter (1986) refer to the
“freezing” of electoral patterns after what they call “founding
elections”; public financing of parties depending upon how well they
performed in Duma elections; was clearly intended to bolster the
position of Russia’s biggest parties (United Russia)
- Chhibber et al. (2014): India; the organizational structure of
parties can have a large and independent impact on the effective number
of parties, since it alters the incentive structure for politicians to
stay within a party, to defect to another party, or to form a new party;
in Indian states where the parties that compete are more organized, not
only is the effective number of parties lower, but so is the volatility
of the party system
- Gryzmala-Busse (2017): the cruel paradox is that the biggest
boosters and builders of party democracy—the reinvented authoritarian
successor parties—eventually suffer the most electorally; their embrace
of democratic party competition both levels the playing field and
increases the consensus over liberal democracy as a desideratum; yet it
does nothing to protect them from electoral retribution, if anything,
reinvented autocrats are punished much more heavily by voters than other
parties; the irony was that these reinvented parties established the
high standards by which they would be judged; these standards could not
be met, all the more so because electoral success led to the expansion
of organizations and funding that made regional challenges and corrupt
financial deals almost inevitable; these parties were unable to uphold
their credibility as expert managers, a problem that was exacerbated by
the fact that their electoral success made them less cohesive and
discipline e.g. Poland and Hungary
Electoral system choice
- Duverger (1954): the simple-majority single-ballot system
i.e. simple plurality rule in single-member districts favors the
two-party system (1) voters will avoid wasting their votes on hopeless
third party candidacies (2) elites will avoid wasting their time, money,
and effort in launching what the voters will perceive as hopeless
candidacies, instead forming coalitions of sufficient size to win a
plurality
- Cox (1997): “making votes count”; there is a significant interaction
between social heterogeneity and electoral structure (1) the translation
of social cleavages into partisan preferences (2) the translation of
partisan preferences into votes (3) the translation of votes into seats;
bi-partism arises because of (1) a strong electoral system (2) few
cleavages; multi-partism arises because of (1) many exploitable
cleavages (2) a permissive electoral system
- Boix (1997/1999): proportional representation was adopted in those
countries in which the socialist party was strong and nonsocialist
parties controlled roughly similar shares of the electorate; failure to
reduce the electoral threshold would have led to an overwhelming victory
of the socialist party (1) consequences of electoral rules (2)
calculations of rulers and the stability of the electoral arena (3) the
reform of the electoral system as a function of the viability of the old
party system (5) the strength of the new entering parties (6) the
coordinating capacity of the ruling parties
- Kalyvas (1996): party system change; cleavages are not fixed;
liberal anti-clericalism at the end of the nineteenth century led the
Church to self-defensive strategies, with the eventual outcome,
unintended by the Church, of the establishment of Christian Democratic
parties
- Cusack, Iversen, and Soskice (2007): in countries where the right
was divided by religious and other non-economic cleavages, and unable to
coordinate, they chose proportional representation as a defensive move
to prevent electoral elimination by a rising left (1) PR for
redistribution (minimal winning coalitions) (2) PR for consociationalism
and corporatism (oversized coalitions and inclusion); for those right
and center parties that represented organized groups in the economy, and
that had developed cooperative relations with unions, the benefits from
the adoption of PR of consensual regulatory politics outweighed the
costs of exclusion from minimum winning coalitions in redistributive
politics; VoC meets electoral system choice
- Boix (2009): the alignment of party preferences, shaped by their
strategic concerns, was crucial to determine the fortunes of electoral
reform in the advanced world at the turn of the 20th century; the actual
introduction of PR depended also on each country’s specific
constitutional system and, particularly, on both the partisan
composition of parliament and actual parliamentary negotiations taking
place within each chamber and across chambers
- Ahmed (2012): the choice of electoral systems ultimately turned, not
on partisan interests in seat maximization or the dictates of economic
coordination as has been postulated, but rather by the need to minimize
the existential threat posed by worker’s parties to the social order,
and particularly the institutions of capitalism and liberal
democracy
Presidentialism vs. parlamentarism
- Cox (1987): the “efficient secret”; large constituencies are
difficult to buy off with bribery and patronage; instead, programmatic
(i.e. policy) appeals are far more effective which required activity
parliamentary activity; led to the curtailing of individual MPs’ rights
(against resistance from backbenchers); the Cabinet emerged as an
executive-legislative body that predominated party-centric
elections
- Linz (1990): the “perils of presientialsim”; (1) nature of
presidentialism as a zero-sum game (bare-majority not represented
i.e. disproportionality) (2) problem of dual legitimacy (presidential
party vs. legislative party i.e. dismissal of the legislature) (3)
president elected for a fixed term (impeachment i.e. criminal
charges)
- Shugart and Carey (1992): huge variety of institutional arrangements
for assembly-executive relations in systems generally grouped together
as presidential; cabinet; plurality vs. PR; veto-power; etc.
- Tsebelis (1995): “veto-players”; increased number of veto players
and increased ideological distance increases difficulty of departing
from status quo
Weighting the debate
- Cheibub and Limongi (2002/2007): the problem of presidential
democracy is not that they are “institutionally flawed”; rather, the
problem is the they exist in societies where democracies of any type are
likely to be unstable; no country that had a presidential constitution
under democracy re-emerged under a parliamentary constitution;
presidential systems seem to emerge after military regimes while
parliamentary systems seem to emerge out of countries that are richer
and have more established institutions
- Chaisty et al. (2014): the surprising sustainability of multiparty
presidentialism in new democracies; presidential toolbox for
constructing legislative coalitions (1) agenda power (2) budgetary
authority (3) cabinet management (4) partisan powers (5) informal
institutions
Legislatures and regime type
- Hale (2005): “regime cycles”; “patronal presidentialism” (1) formal
presidential term limits i.e. incumbent lame duck (2) public opinion (3)
international intervention; movement towards liberal democracy is more
likely to emerge from political stalemate than from the victory of one
side (Rustow, 1970)
- Fish (2006): “stronger legislatures, stronger democracies”; weakness
of legislatures undermine “horizontal accountability” (O’Donnell);
constitutional choice; strong presidency; in Russia, presidential abuse
of power, committed in the presence of a legislature that cannot curb
such abuse even when it is inclined to do so, has been a hallmark of
post-communist politics
Populist parties
- Ignazi (1992): the rise of neoconservatism in the 1980s i.e. the
“silent revolution” (Inglehart, 1977) pushed the main-stream right to
re-emphasized authority, patriotism, and traditional moral values;
provoked, directly or indirectly, a higher polarization both in terms of
ideological distance and in terms of ideological intensity; led to a
decline in identification with established parties and, in extremism,
with the political system; created political space for populist radical
right parties, particularly when mainstream right-wing parties moved
back to the center
- Weyland (2001): populism is best defined as a political strategy;
power capability that types of rulers use to sustain themselves
politically; under populism the ruler is an individual, a personalistic
leader, not a group or organization; populism rests on the power
capability of numbers; emerges when personalistic leaders base their
rule on massive yet mostly un-institutionalized support from large
numbers
- Mudde (2004/2014): “populist radical right” (1) nativism (2)
authoritarianism (3) populism; populism as a “thin ideology”; split
society into two homogenous and antagonistic groups (1) the pure people
(2) the corrupt elite on the other; populists guided by the “will of the
people”
- Megiud (2007): “niche parties” are those, including the radical
right, that reject the traditional class‐based orientation of politics,
focus on novel issues that do not coincide with the typical left‐right
political dimension, and limit their issue appeals
- Mair (2009/2013):the increasing influence of global markets and
international institutions is seriously limiting the maneuvering room of
political actors at the national level; the Great Recession forced
mainstream parties in Southern Europe to converge on a “responsible”
pro-austerity program, which sparked the rise of populist radical left
parties; SYRIZA in Greece and Podemos in Spain; as well as in Latin
America e.g. Bolivia (Evo Morales), Ecuador (Rafael Correa), and
Venezuela (Hugo Chávez); the willingness of certain segments of the
electorate to prioritize the rise of a “responsive” government over a
liberal democratic one
- Bustikova (2009/2014): mainstream party convergence due to “vacuum
effects” on the policy space of party competition (1) economic
restructuring (2) EU accession; opened up space for the radical right
within the post-communist party system; “minority accommodation”
- Hanson (2010): political ideologies” are typically necessary
(although not sufficient) for the mobilization of enduring, independent
national party organizations in uncertain democracies because they help
to overcome collective action problems e.g. France, Germany, Russia
- Albertazzi and McDonnell (2015): “populists in power”; the electoral
strength of populists, coupled with the corresponding erosion in support
for mainstream parties, has meant that they are increasingly accepted as
coalition partners by mainstream parties; populists in all cases kept
putting forward proposals and championing initiatives that repeatedly,
consistently and purposely clashed with the fundamental tenets of
liberal democracy
- Kaltwasser, et al. (2017): (1) ideational (a set of ideas that not
only depicts society as divided between “the pure people” versus “the
corrupt elite” but also claims that politics is about respecting popular
sovereignty at any cost) (Mudde, 2004) (2) political-strategic (Weyland)
(3) socio-cultural (break taboos)
- Abou-Chadhi and Krause (2018): regression discontinuity approach;
radical right success causally affects mainstream parties’ positions;
cause a strong move towards an anti-immigrant stance by other political
parties; the transformation of the political space in Western Europe
that we are currently witnessing is not simply a reaction to shifting
preferences of the European electorate, but is a result of the strategic
interaction of political parties
- Mudde and Kaltwasser (2018): (1) economic anxiety (2) cultural
backlash (3) the tension between responsiveness and responsibility (4)
(negative) partisanship and polarization; limited programmatic scope;
attached to other ideological elements i.e. right-wing nativism or
left-wing socialism; populism is at odds with liberal democracy
(minority rights, rule of law, and separation of powers); supply-side
vs. demand-side; cultural backlash vs. economic anxiety linked to
populism per se or the populist radical right in particular; populist
radical right parties are particularly successful in European countries
marked by economic prosperity, low unemployment, and generous social
welfare policies; “social envy” via Lipset (1955) “status politics”;
populism as a moral clash between the “pure people” and the “corrupt
elite” whereas nativism refers to the ethnic division between “insiders”
and “outsiders”
Political Economy
Markets in society
- Locke (1690): “property and freedom”; economic freedom as
indispensable toward the achievement of political freedom; co-operation
is strictly individual and voluntary “provided” that enterprises are
private and that individuals are effectively free to enter or not to
enter into any particular exchange i.e. government is essential both as
a forum for determining the “rules of the game” and as an umpire to
interpret and enforce the rules decided upon
- Smith (1776): division of labor; “dexterity” of socio-economic
differentiation ; the “invisible hand” of the market via self-interest
and competition (comparative advantage, see: Ricardo, 1817)
- Marx (1867): capital and labor; class interests fundamentally
exploitative as workers are compelled to sell their own labor power and
are deprived of the means of production; “alienation”
- Durkheim (1897): functionalist division of labor (e.g. organism) BUT
“anomie” e.g. suicide
- Weber (1922): “social action”; traditions and customs;
rational-legal institutions (e.g. hierarchy, impersonal, division of
labor); the “calling” and the ascetic “spirit of capitalism”
(i.e. Protestant work ethic); double-entry book-keeping
Markets in the state
- Polanyi (1944): markets do not spontaneously arise, governments
actively create them; “double movement” in which trading classes promote
economic liberalism to foster a self-regulating market, but the working
and landed classes push for social protection aimed at conserving man
and nature; re-embedding the market to try to create a web of norms and
protection around the market; politics as constitutive of the economy;
Speenhamland Law to protect farmers
- Shonfield (1965): “modern capitalism” via “market steering”
i.e. state interventionism (1) the management of the economic system (2)
Keynesian demand stimulus, the welfare state, and expanded public
expenditures (3) the “taming” of “the violence of the market” in the
private sector, thanks to government regulation, planning, and
inter-firm cooperation (4) policies to increase innovation and worker
training (5) the pursuit of intellectual coherence through long-term
planning
- Katzenstein (1978): strong states lead their economies, while weak
states allow economic interests to operate on their own; dense networks
involve high degrees of coordination, while loose networks cannot avoid
unit autonomy
- Gourevitch (1986): societal actors divide and combine over time in
ways that relate to their changing situations in the international
division of labor; “production profile explanation” in which economic
interests make coalitions that have preferences which are shaped by
actors’ situation in international economy
Globalization and capitalism
- Ruggie (1982): “embedded liberalism”; the compromise of embedded
liberalism has never been fully extended to the developing countries;
subject to the orthodox stabilization measures of the IMF;
liberalization produced by the GATT has benefited relatively few
developing countries; Bretton Woods adjustment processes worked
primarily to devalue the currencies of deficit countries, sacrificing
economic efficiency to social stability
- Milner and Keohane (1996): (1) partisan composition of the
government in office (2) organization of labor and financial markets (3)
political institutions; internationalization is expected to generate new
coalitions revolving around the differential effects of greater
openness; tradables producers favoring devaluations vs. non-tradeables
sectors opposing them; owners of specific factors, whose capital is
immobile vs. holders of liquid assets; the loss of policy autonomy may
place special pressure on left-wing, social democratic governments
- Garrett (1998): globalization threatens the prosperity, stability
and legitimacy of the democratic state itself (1) increasing exposure to
trade (2) multi-nationalization of production (3) integration of
financial markets; institutions as collective goods that cannot be
supplied by the market; rather than becoming increasingly irrelevant,
domestic political factors such as the partisan balance of political
power and the strength of organized labor movements are at least as
important today as they have ever been to the course of economic
policy
- Friedman (1999): the democratization of technology, finance (“the
electronic herd”); information; the “golden straitjacket” i.e. no major
ideological alternatives; “one size fits all” pinches certain groups,
squeezes others and keeps a society under pressure to constantly
streamline its economic institutions and upgrade its performance;
leaving people behind as the economy grows and politics shrinks
Institutions
- North (1981/1990): institutions are “the rules of the game” of a
society and reduce transaction costs as they organize exchange (1)
institutions are a set of rules, formal or informal, that actors
generally follow, whether for normative, cognitive, or material reasons
(2) organizations are durable entities with formally recognized members,
whose rules also contribute to the institutions of the political
economy
Varieties of capitalism (VoC)
- Hall and Soskice (2001): (1) liberal market economies (LMEs) in
which firms coordinate their activities primarily via hierarchies for
internal issues and competitive market arrangements for external issues
(2) coordinated market economies (CMEs) in which firms depend more
heavily on non-market relationships to coordinate their endeavors with
other actors; rely on collaborative, not competitive, relationships to
build the competencies of the firm; institutional complementarities
reinforce the differences between varieties of capitalism
- Thelen (2001): “alternative face of globalization”; increasingly
integrated global markets have heightened the competitive pressures that
many firms face; when firms compete on the basis of quality and
reliability in the context of just-in-time production, the capacity to
adjust depends rather heavily on stable and cooperative relations with
labor
- Thelen (2014): “varieties of liberalization” (1) deregulation, often
associated with liberal market economies (2) liberalization as
dualization, associated especially with continental European political
economies like Germany (3) liberalization through socially embedded
flexibilization, typically associated with the Scandinavian cases
Critiques of VoC
- Vogel (2001): German and Japanese firms (CMEs) are distinct from
their liberal, Anglo-American counterparts (LMEs) in that they are less
favorable toward labor market liberalization, adjust to shocks through
internal labor market flexibility (reorganizing/retraining) rather than
external labor market flexibility (hiring/firing), rely more on
cooperative relations with labor and less on labor flexibility; BUT
German and Japanese variants of CME differ in important ways (1) German
government has gone further in codifying its economic model in law,
whereas the Japanese model rests more on informal networks and standard
practices (2) German labor is more powerful than Japanese labor in both
politics and corporate management
- Levy (2006): “new state activities in the age of liberalization”;
welfare state politics are no longer about Shonfeld (1965)
market-steering but rather market-supporting (1) corrective i.e. making
labor markets and systems of social protection more employment friendly
(2) constructive i.e. recasting regulatory frameworks to permit
countries to cross major economic and technological divides and
expanding market competition in industry and services at home and
abroad; guide post-Fordism
- Iverson, Soskice, and Xu (2017): “transition to the knowledge
economy and the new skill cleavage”; ICT revolution unraveled these
interdependencies and created a disjuncture between an old middle class,
which was increasingly marginalized by technological change, and a new
educated middle class that thrived; the consequence of “middle class
encapsulation” was to create a greater preference gap between both the
old middle class and those above, and between the old middle class and
those below
Welfare state and “power resource” theory
- Korpi and Esping-Anderson (1986): relative power position of labor’s
“power resources” (1) organizational strength of labor unions, often
measured in union density (2) relative power of labor’s political
allies, especially social democratic political parties, and this is
usually captured in a measure of left party participation in government;
Scandinavia, Austria, and Germany have reformist social-democratic
parties with strong ties to national union movements which have
dominated working class politics; Sweden strongest with a centralized
union confederation which works closely with the social democratic
party; Austria similar but institutionalized religious and political
cleavages; German movement is weakest (close ties with German social
democrats but the party is electorally weak and has remained in
opposition)
- Esping-Anderson (1990): the “three worlds of welfare capitalism” (1)
liberal welfare states in which unions are weak (<15%) and social
democratic parties are either weaker still or altogether absent
e.g. US/Canada (means-tested assistance; modest universal transfers;
modest social insurance) (2) corporatist-statist i.e. Christian
Democratic countries in which there are medium levels of union
organization (typically 20%–40%) and somewhat less dominant social
democratic parties e.g. Austria/France/Germany/Italy in which welfare
regimes are based on a social insurance model in which benefits are tied
to occupational status (redistributive impact is negligible and shaped
by the Church i.e. non-working wives, day care, family services) (3)
Social Democratic countries characterized by both high levels of union
organization (density rates of 60% and higher) and social democratic
parties that are frequently in government e.g. Scandinavia (universalism
and de-commodification extended to the new middle classes)
- Immergut (1992): the logic of health policy making via differential
political institutions (1) majority parliamentarism in Sweden
i.e. executive government rested on secure parliamentary majorities (2)
direct parliamentary rule in France i.e. unstable parliamentary
coalitions and lack of party discipline impeded executive governments
from enacting legislation (3) direct democracy in Switzerland
i.e. threat of negative referenda produced parliamentary paralysis,
allowing any and all interest groups unfettered access to defeat
national health insurance proposals again and again
- Pierson (1996): welfare state “retrenchment”; retrenchment is
generally an exercise in blame avoidance rather than credit claiming;
unpopularity of welfare state “retrenchment” makes major cutbacks
unlikely except under conditions of budgetary crisis, and radical
restructuring is unlikely even then
- Rodrik (1998): government spending plays a risk-reducing role in
economies exposed to a significant amount of external risk;
risk-mitigating role of government spending should be displayed most
prominently in social security and welfare spending, particularly in
advanced economies
- Iverson and Cusack (2000): the impact of common trends such as
globalization or deindustrialization is heavily mediated by the strength
of left political parties; governments have responded to the
transformation of the employment structure (1) employment in private
services (2) expansion of the state’s public insurance functions in
order to compensate for the risks associated with often very large
employment losses in the traditional sectors (3) heavy regulation of
labor and product markets has hampered a major expansion of private
sector service employment; deindustrialization will be associated with
increasingly distinct partisan effects
- Huber and Stephens (2001): partisan politics is the single most
important factor shaping the development of welfare state outcomes,
especially the dominant political orientation of incumbent governments
in the postwar years; the nature of production regimes in which the
welfare state is embedded is important in shaping options and choices;
inclusion of women in the labor force has a strong interactive effect
with the expansion of social welfare services
- Rueda (2007): powerful social democratic parties allied with strong
labor movements may well promote, rather than inhibit, inequality;
between (1) labor-market “insiders,” i.e., core workers who have jobs
and who are intent on preserving their relatively privileged position
within the labor market (2) labor-market “outsiders” who either do not
have jobs or are in more precarious forms of employment and thus do not
enjoy the same package of wages and benefits as insiders; highlights
intra-class conflict over policy options
- Haggard and Kaufman (2008): (1) ‘stratified’ Latin American welfare
states characterized by relatively generous social insurance systems for
civil servants and organized formal-sector workers coupled with
widespread exclusion of informal urban workers and the rural sector BUT
low coverage (2) universal coverage for all segments of the population
in Eastern Europe (3) East Asian welfare systems emphasized public
education and healthcare; limited social insurance and security, mainly
through mandated individual savings schemes BUT more egalitarian
- Gingrich (2011): variation in market outcomes follows from who built
the market and whether the existing institutions allow them to appeal to
the electorate and their particular constituents; shaped by left
vs. right partisan preferences i.e. blame shifting and reward claiming;
the Left will implement market reforms in order to protect the
legitimacy of the welfare state, whereas the Right will implement market
reforms to undercut the welfare state
Development
Modernization theory
- W. W. Rostow (1960): “the stages of economic growth”
Limits of modernization theory
- Gerschenkron (1962): pressures for high-speed industrialization are
inherent in preindustrial situations of backward countries; policies
toward backward countries are unlikely to be successful if they ignore
the basic peculiarities of backwardness
- Moore (1966): social classes condition political and economic paths
for development; multiple outcomes; modernization in one country changes
it for all subsequent countries; modernization begins with peasant
revolutions that fail
- Huntington (1968): “gap hypothesis” between rapid economic growth
and modernization and political discontent and unrest
Theories of backwardness
- Fichte (1664): early statist theory of economic development; the
“closed trading state” in Germany had to not only protect the rights and
property of its citizens, but actively regulate the economy and society
in order to make Germany competitive with England
- List (1841): “underdeveloped” countries needed a strong state to
protect domestic businesses and economic gains from the destabilizing
effects of foreign investments and external markets
- Veblen (1915): late developers had a “situational advantage” in that
they could simply borrow the most advanced technology available without
incurring the costs, trials, and tribulations; and a means to break down
more rapidly traditional habits and customs
- Lenin (1917): “imperialism as the highest stage of capitalism”;
world-systemic explanation of international underdevelopment; the
concentration of monopoly capital in the hands of the bankers in
conjunction with the export of goods to new markets in the colonies
permitted the international bourgeoisie to maintain its economic and
political power and circumvent the absolution immiseration of the masses
(working classes) at home; peripheral regions as the “weakest links” in
the capitalist world-system
Effects of backwardness
- Gunder Frank (1970): “the development of underdevelopment”;
underdevelopment linked to capitalism; each metropolis serves to impose
and maintain a monopolistic structure and exploitative relationship;
satellites experience their greatest economic development and especially
their most classically capitalist industrial development if and when
their ties to their metropolis are weakest; “underdevelopment … is the
necessary product of four centuries of capitalism itself”
- Wallerstein (1974): “world-systems theory”; three structural
positions in the world-economy (1) core (2) periphery (3)
semi-periphery
- Cardoso (1973/1979): challenged key assumption of modernization
paradigm—that poor countries would follow same path as developed and
that underdevelopment of periphery was uniformly caused by exploitation
of developed capitalist economies; development in dependent economies
creates a restricted, limited, and upper class oriented type of market
and society (attracting investment by providing low wages and other
incentives to investors)
- Hirschman (1982): capitalism is an extraordinarily powerful force
that dissolves all previous social formations and ideologies and even
chips away at capitalism’s own moral foundations; cannot do everything
at once
- Evans, Rueschemeyer, and Skocpol (1985): “bringing the state back
in”
Developmental State
Varieties
- Haggard (1986/1990): development strategies are packages of policies
aimed at steering economic activity (1) ISI in Brazil and Mexico (2) EOI
in South Korea and Taiwan (3) entrepôt in Hong Kong and Singapore;
international market pressures vs. domestic political pressures; in the
face of external shocks, larger developing countries such as Argentina,
Brazil, and Mexico, particularly those endowed with natural resources,
could continue financing ISI; more likely to move into secondary import
substitution (“deepening”) than smaller countries that lacked natural
resources and when hit with external shocks, these smaller,
resource-poor economies were more likely to adjust by following the
model of export-oriented industrialization
- Evans (1996): “embedded autonomy”; concrete set of connections
between state and particular social groups is a necessary condition for
a performing developmental state; predatory vs. developmental state
institutions; role of the state in markets; efficacious states combine
well-developed, bureaucratic internal organization with dense
public-private ties; capacity depends on putting autonomy (protecting
the state from capture) and embeddedness (sources of intelligence and
channels of implementation i.e. bureaucracy)
- Waldner (1999): levels of elite conflict determine whether state
transformation occurred simultaneously with or before popular
incorporation; in Korea and Taiwan state building preceded popular
incorporation; Korean and Taiwanese elite were not indebted to support
of popular classes at time of institutional transformation they were
able to shape new institutions that proved to be more conducive to
economic development; in Syria and Turkish elites initiate new rounds of
state building under conditions of intense conflict that divided the
elite and militated against compromise (“precocious Keynesianism”) that
committed states to growth-inhibiting transfers
- Rodrik (2007): kick start; government intervention, policy biases
and politically connected firms, institutional failures, and high levels
of policy uncertainty and risk create dualistic economic structures and
repress entrepreneurship; get it going and get out of the way; sustained
economic growth needs high-quality institutions over the long-term;
protection of property rights and rule of law; some have seen success
under authoritarianism but many others have not
East Asia
- Johnson (1982/1987): “Japanese miracle” of state-led development;
powerful, talented, prestige-laden economic bureaucracy; Ministry of
International Trade and Industry (MITI); complex of policies concerning
protection of domestic industries, development of strategic industries,
and adjustment of the economic structure in anticipation of shocks;
industrial rationalization and industrial structure; institutions
underpin government-business relationship in Japan and South Korea;
wartime controls provided the postwar planners with an unusual array of
instruments for influencing industry, despite the American occupation:
(1) control over all foreign exchange and imports of technology, which
gave them the power to choose industries for development (2) the ability
to dispense preferential financing, tax breaks, and protection from
foreign competition, which gave them the power to lower the costs of the
chosen industries (3) the authority to order the creation of cartels and
bank-based industrial conglomerates, which gave them the power to
supervise competition
- Wade (1990): “market-supremacy” interpretations of East Asian
economic success (1) economic openness and small government, the
limitations of small domestic markets were overcome by exporting
manufactured goods at competitive prices (2) government intervention
that promoted exports and offset market failures (3) external demand
generated by the rhythm of Western capital accumulation linked to
Western defense against communism (4) synergistic connection between a
public system and a mostly private market system; i.e. the allocation of
resources and state action to address market failures
- Kohli (2004): (1) neopatrimonial states (Nigeria) weakly
centralized, barely legitimate authority structures, personalistic
leaders, corrupt bureaucracy (2) fragmented-multiclass states (India,
Brazil (civ)) ‘modern’ states, authority, public arena but rely on broad
class alliance & pursue several competing politicized policies (3)
cohesive-capitalist states (South Korea, Brazil (mil)) centralized,
rapid economic growth via national security, links with capital, control
of labor, competent bureaucrats
Africa
- Bates (1981): industrial firm workers and owners, economic and
political elites, privileged farmers, and managers of public
bureaucracies constitute development coalition in contemporary Africa;
they reap benefits and costs are distributed widely but fall especially
hard on the unorganized masses of farming population
Post-communist transitions
- Sachs (1991): “shock treatment”
- Balcerowicz (1994): “extraordinary politics”; the brevity of the
exceptional period means that a radical economic program, launched as
quickly as possible after the breakthrough, has a much greater chance of
being accepted than either a delayed radical program or a nonracial
alternative that introduces difficult measures in piecemeal fashion
- Fish (1998): roots of Russia’s “racket economy” (1) extraordinary
natural resource endowment (2) privatization that creates new oligarchy
(3) withdrawal of the state from law enforcement (4) moral vacuum (5)
weak societal organization; the desperate state of the state; “solved”
by a president who is both intent upon exercising power within the
confines of the law and who is willing and able to coerce
i.e. Putin
- Hellman (1998): “J-curve”; reforms are expected to make things worse
before they get better; instead of forming a constituency in support of
advancing reforms, the short-term winners have often sought to stall the
economy in a “partial reform equilibrium” that generates concentrated
rents for themselves, while imposing high costs on the rest of society;
the process of economic reform is threatened less by the net losers than
by the net winners
- Schwartz (2006): economic reform policies that fail to devote
sufficient attention to the formation of legal and regulatory
institutions breed corruption and criminality, leading to economic
stagnation; rapid neoliberal privatization unaccompanied by institution
building fosters a politics of greed, not a politics of democracy;
during transition periods, it is not institutions that structure
politics but politics that shape the design of institutions (a series of
political struggles among powerful interest groups)
China
- Woo/Wu (2003): role of “state owned enterprises”; (1) Chinese
enterprise were able to “grow out of plan” without the SOEs releasing
their labor only because of the great reservoir of surplus agricultural
workers; policy experimentation (free-trade enclaves, TVEs, etc.);
gradualism due to the absence of policy consensus
- Qian (2012): (1) dual-track liberalization (2) local government
ownership i.e. rural township-village enterprises (TVEs) (3) fiscal
federalism aligning interests of local governments with local business
(4) anonymous banking to limit government predation in the absence of
the rule of law (5) failure to reform the large scale state-owned
enterprises (SOEs)
- Tsai (2015): considerable progress can be achieved even in the
absence of ideal institutions; BUT changes of practice within existing
institutions; “adaptive informal institutions” as opposed to the
creation of new institutions
Challenges to development
- Scott (1998): legibility of a society provides capacity for
large-scale social engineering, high modernist ideology provides the
desire, the authoritarian state provides the determination to act of
that desire, and an incapacitate civil society provides the leveled
social terrain on which to build
- De Soto (2008): “capitalist apartheid” will continue until we all
come to terms with critical flaw in many countries’ legal and political
systems that prevents the majority from entering the formal property
system; property rights as key in the developing world; “dead” or
“dormant” capital; much of the marginalization of the poor in developing
and former communist nations come from their inability to benefit from
the six effects that formal property provides
- Lal (2008): “dirigism”; price mechanism supplanted by direct
government control to promote economic development; neoclassical
economics is unrealistic because of its behavioral, technological, and
institutional assumptions; concerned primarily with the efficient
allocation of given resources and hence could deal with neither
so-called dynamic assets of growth nor with various ethical aspects of
the alleviation of poverty or the distribution of income needed for
development
Globalization and development
- Garrett (1998): “shrinking states”; globalization threatens the
prosperity, stability and legitimacy of the democratic state itself (1)
increasing exposure to trade (2) multi-nationalization of production (3)
integration of financial markets
- Stiglitz (2007): “globalization and its discontents”; emphasis on
how globalization is managed; globalization of knowledge has brought
improved health, with life spans increasing at a rapid pace, BUT the
most adverse effects have arisen from the liberalization of financial
and capital markets, which has posed risks to developing countries
without commensurate rewards; trans-national volatility; governance
through “Washington Consensus” e.g. intellectual property rights:
invention vs. diffusion
- Keohane and Milner (2010): internationalization is expected to
generate new coalitions revolving around the differential effects of
greater openness (1) partisan composition of the government in office
(2) organization of labor and financial markets (3) political
institutions
Re-visiting the developmental state
- Evans, Huber, and Stevens (2017): “the political foundations of
state effectiveness” via the Sen-Ostrom nexus (1999-1996) i.e. “human
capabilities”; the foundations of capability expansion are collective
goods (1) early childhood education (2) preventative public health
expenditure; incentivizing and supporting investment in industrial
activity is a complex task, but delivering quality education or
healthcare to the population requires much greater organizational
capacity and broader support coalitions e.g. Kerala, Brazil (Bolsa
Familia, SUS)
- Haggard (2018): see Haggard (1986/1990) and Haggard and Kaufman
(2008)
Methodology
Philosophies of social science
- Hume (1748): empirical cause/effect but causality cannot be
perceived (our imagination provides the “real” causal link and thus we
impose our own theories on the world); refrain from imposing causal
explanations on the world; avoid causal claims completely; restrict
itself to identifying and observing regularities in the world; focus on
correlations; identify and map factual correlations among facts that are
directly observable by the human senses
- Durkheim (1895): consider social facts as things; socially
constructed and collectively maintained constraints (e.g. norms, rules,
laws, economic organizations, customs, etc.); BUT still conceptual
categories; the contested debates around them drive the production of
knowledge; setting up a puzzle by using a fragment of knowledge as the
starting point; beginning with skepticism and moving towards an
absolute; “forever in the middle” because of the unknowability of the
absolute; the political always between ideal types
- Popper (1959): “falsification” i.e. no amount of evidence can
absolutely confirm a theory; qualitative and quantitative reasoning are
both inductive (from the particular to the general) i.e. looking at the
empirical evidence; but in practice social scientists act pre-Popper;
social-facts are theory-laden and dependent upon ontological arguments;
we cannot achieve absolute certainty but we can falsify wrong
conjectures via theoretical pluralism
- Kuhn (1962): “tipping” paradigms; the most progressive paradigm, the
one best fitting nature, will emerge victorious; a paradigm is born out
of a concrete scientific achievement that resolves or suspends debates
over foundations, assumptions, and/or methods, ushering in a period of
normal science; hostility toward other paradigms, but trapped by
“ordinary language” debate
- Lakatos (1978): criteria to evaluate claims in relation to comparing
rival research programs; assess strengths and weaknesses of rival
viewpoints; a “hard core” surrounded by a “protective belt” of auxiliary
hypotheses that may be progressive (constantly expanding its application
to a larger and larger set of cases or striving for a more precise
treatment of the cases it presently covers) or degenerative
- Giddens (1998): “structuration” (culture/society AND agency);
people’s everyday actions reinforce and reproduce a set of expectations
- and it is this set of other people’s expectations which make up the
‘social forces’ and ‘social structures’ that sociologists talk about;
“society only has form, and that form only has effects on people, in so
far as structure is produced and reproduced in what people do”
Concept formation
- Sartori (1970): does it make sense to construct formalized systems
of quantitatively well-defined relationships so long as we wander in a
mist of qualitatively ill-defined concepts? without discipline,
conceptual mishandling; data mis-gathering; conceptual misinformation;
we must form concepts before we quantify them; we need to know what we
are measuring
- Sartori (1970): relationship between meaning of concepts and the
range of cases to which they apply can be understood in terms of a
“ladder of generalization”; concepts with fewer defining attributes
commonly apply to more cases and are higher on ladder of generality
whereas concepts with more defining attributes apply to fewer cases and
are lower on the “ladder of generality”; concept extension i.e. the
population to which the concept refers; concept intension i.e. the set
of attributes that determine category membership
- Collier and Levitsky (1997): “democracy with adjectives”;
“diminished subtypes” are not clearly defined and suffer from conceptual
stretching; “precising” the definition of democracy by adding defining
attributes modifies the definition of democracy itself
- Adcock and Collier (2001): measurement validity and concept
formation (1) background concept (2) systematized concept (3) indicators
(4) scores for cases
- Gerring and Barresi (2003): “putting ordinary language to work” (1)
a respect for ordinary language (2) disciplining concepts toward
practical (empirical) research (across time and space); minimal
definitions have crisp boundaries (reduce ambiguity); maximal (ideal
typical) definitions have gradations i.e. non-crisp boundaries (degrees
of belonging); sample definitions; typologize and condense attributes;
define (a) minimal (b) maximal (ideal-type) definitions
- Collier and Levitsky (2009): “conceptual hierarchies”; the root
concept of democracy in the literature on the third wave was anchored in
a procedural minimum definition; focused on democratic procedures,
rather than on substantive policies or other outcomes that might be
viewed as democratic; minimal in that it deliberately focused on the
smallest possible number of attributes that still were seen as producing
a viable standard for democracy; e.g. democracy vs. dictatorship
(Przeworski)
- Collier, LaPorte, and Seawright (2012): component indicators can
hide multidimensionality; developing rigorous and useful concepts
entails four interconnected goals (1) clarifying and refining their
meaning (2) establishing an informative and productive connection
between these meanings and the terms used to designate them (3)
situating the concepts within their semantic field, that is, the
constellation of related concepts and terms (4) identifying and refining
the hierarchical relations among concepts, involving kind hierarchies;
employ the 2x2 matrix to diagram conceptual dimensions
Examples of typologies
- Collier and Levitsky (1997): “democracy with adjectives”;
“diminished subtypes” are not clearly defined and suffer from conceptual
stretching; “precising” the definition of democracy by adding defining
attributes modifies the definition of democracy itself
- Hadenius and Teorell (2007): “pathways from authoritarianism”;
degree of competitiveness (1) Geddes: personalist, military, and
single-party regimes (2) Linz and Stepan: post-totalitarianism and
sultanistic; Larry Diamond: “hybrid regimes”; Levitsky and Way:
competitive authoritarianism; Schedler: “electoral
authoritarianism”
- Soifer (2008/2017): state capacity (1) GDP per capita (2) luminosity
(3) literacy (4) tax ratio; survey approach = the state’s reach across
territory, its ability to impose taxation, and its effectiveness in the
provision of property rights
- Reeskens and Hooghe (2010): civic-ethnic dichotomy of citizenship;
being born in the country is shown to be the clearest expression of
ethnic citizenship, while adhering to the laws of the country is the
main criterion for civic citizenship, BUT for an ethnic conception of
citizenship it is clear that obeying the laws is not sufficient to
become a full member of the community
- Kriesi (2015): “varieties of democracy” (1) consensus-majoritarian
dimension (2) federalist-unitary dimension (3) illiberal-liberal
dimension (4) direct-representative dimension; minimalist democracy
(exclusive elections) polyarchy (electoral democracy plus the rule of
law); liberal democracy (electoral democracy, plus the rule of law, plus
civil rights)
Institutionalisms
- Tilly (1984): “big structures, large processes, huge comparisons”
i.e. “macro-history”
- Geddes (1990): institutionalists see politics as somewhat autonomous
from the economy; political outcomes are not necessarily continuous or
smoothly moving and evolving; adjustments are seen as incremental;
historical institutionalism (actor motivation is self-interest, power
resources and authority matter); rational choice institutionalism
(utility maximization over preferences); sociological institutionalism
(stability of groups)
- Hall and Taylor (1996): (1) historical i.e. “asymmetries of power”
along with path dependence and unintended consequences (2) rational
choice i.e. behavioral assumptions and strategic interactions (3)
sociological i.e. “frames of meaning”, symbols, and moral templates
- Helmke and Levitsky (2004): “informal institutions” (1)
complementary (2) accommodating (3) competing (4) substitutive
- Mahoney and Thelen (2010): “gradual institutional change” (1)
displacement (2) layering (3) drift (4) conversion; institutions
represent compromises based on specific coalitional dynamics that are
always vulnerable to shifts; compliance is complicated by the fact that
rules can never be precise enough to cover the complexities of all
situations and actors cannot anticipate every situation
- Riker (1980): the “Riker objection” institutions are socially
constructed equilibria that emerge from the strategic behavior of
individuals i.e. institutions cannot be causes of anything, for they are
merely epiphenomenal on individual preferences and the broader strategic
environment; institutions are constraints except when decisive
coalitions decide they are not e.g. the Rikerian perspective on
institutions would predict that if authoritarian institutions do what
existing theories predict that they do, then institutions should be
least likely to constrain behavior in these settings (1) the presence of
dominant parties (2) the nature of institutional rules (3) forms of
legislative competition (4) other aspects of authoritarian institutions
will reflect the distribution of power in authoritarian regimes rather
than exogenously shaping it
Quantitative
- King, Keohane, and Verba (1994): the same logic should apply to
quantitative and qualitative work and that we need to apply the same
degree of rigor in qualitative and quantitative, the “logic of
inference” is the same in the two methodological approaches;
transparency; causal vs. descriptive inference; estimates of
uncertainty
- Laitin (2002): tripartite methodology (1) statistical regularities
through cross-sectional data; theory/formal theory; case studies
(narrative)
- Lieberman (2005): “nested analysis”; stronger basis for causal
inference than the sum of its parts; suppose you start with a large-N
study, then if the results are satisfactory, use small-N to test model,
if doesn’t fit, use small-N to either repeat model testing or do model
building; if the results are unsatisfactory, use small-N to build model,
then if more coherent, use large-N, then if satisfactory, use small-N to
test model
- Dunning (2012): “natural experiments” in the social sciences; a
“design-based” approach; attempting to identify and analyze real-world
situations in which some process of random or as-if random assignment
places cases in alternative categories of the key independent
variable
Qualitative
- Lijphart (1971): “many variables, small-N”; increase number of cases
geographically, over time, or within-case; combine variables that
express an essentially similar underlying characteristic; focus on
comparable cases similar in important characteristics (constants) but
dissimilar in key variables; focus the analysis on only the key
variables (parsimony)
- Bates (1997): tension between area studies and political
science
- Collier (1998): qualitative comparative method as “separate and
equal”
- Pierson (2000/2003): specific patterns of timing and sequence
matter; “path dependency”; “critical junctures”; time horizons can alter
cause-effects; large consequences may result from relatively “small” or
contingent events; logic of “increasing returns”
- Mahoney and Rusechemeyer (2003): “comparative historical analysis”;
“knowledge accumulation”; new theories inspire new research
programs
- Kitschelt (2003): shallow explanations without depth are empty, deep
explanations without mechanisms are blind (Kant); what affects
deliberate, calculated political action works often through longer
chains of causal determination than short-term mechanisms
- Brady, Collier,and Seawright (2004): KKV suggest an imposition of a
quantitative framework on qualitative work; limitations of quantitative
methods (1) real word data is observational (statistical techniques
designed for experimental situations) (2) increasing sample size pushes
toward generality (3) conceptualization and measurement (4) little
theory (5) selection bias and significance-hacking
- Gerring (2007): case-study approach (1) ability to understand causal
processes (2) not limited to qualitative techniques (3) good case chosen
by doing some initial cross-case analysis to determine what this is a
case of (to counter external validity concerns (4) process tracing
- Pierson (2007): costs of quantitative hegemony (1) narrowly focused
inquiry (2) insufficient attention to substance (3) omission of crucial
political issues (4) inattentiveness to context (5) inattentiveness to
macro configurations (6) inattentiveness to scope conditions
- Slater and Ziblatt (2013): “controlled comparison”; quantitative
analysis establishes internal validity while case study gives external
validity (typically viewed as doing the reverse); explain variation in
government performance across closely matched cases; external validity
requires that cases be selected precisely to control for rival existing
hypothesis